Among the most masterful and insightful of 20th Century economists, Friedrich Hayek alone could have stood shoulder-to-shoulder with his great rival, John Maynard Keynes. Trained by Wieser and Böhm-Bawerk in the Austrian tradition at Vienna, Friedrich A. Hayek nonetheless carved a distinct spot in the economic pantheon – in some ways more different from the Austrian School than that of his friend and intellectual companion, Ludwig von Mises.
After some fundamental early contributions (e.g. his 1928 article is often credited with having introduced the concept of a fully intertemporal equilibrium), Hayek’s early work was primarily in monetary cycle theory (1929, 1931, 1939). Drawing upon the “cumulative process” of Knut Wicksell and a Continental tradition of multi-sectoral overinvestment models, Hayek argued that when finance permitted investment to be greater than savings, then both desired investment and consumption demand cannot be met by actual output – thus there will be forced saving and changing degrees of ‘capital intensity’ (with capital conceived in a very Austrian sense) changing output and employment. However, forced savings are not sustainable as capital goods demand will not be maintained if consumer goods producers are being dried of consumption demand. Thus, there is a contraction in output and a subsequent fall in capital intensity. Hayek argued that this “concertina” process was the main motor behind business cycles.
Friedrich Hayek presented his main treatise on monetary cycle theory in a slim book, Prices and Production (1931), in England and was immediately drafted by Lord Robbins to join the London School of Economics – where he would serve as that institution’s answer to Cambridge’s John Maynard Keynes who was then working on similar issues. Keynes did not take lightly the criticisms Hayek made of his Treatise on Money (1930), and thus Keynes and Piero Sraffa joined forces to bury Hayek and his cycle theory in the Economic Journal in 1932.
At the London School of Economics, Hayek was instrumental in furthering its then-novel “continental” bent and he was highly influential on his junior colleagues (such as John Hicks) and students (which included Abba Lerner and Nicholas Kaldor). However, following the appearance of the General Theory by John Maynard Keynes in 1936, Abba Lerner and Nicholas Kaldor, like the rest of the economics profession, were drawn away from Hayek’s orbit. Nicholas Kaldor’s departure was particularly stinging – since his subsequent criticisms of the ‘Ricardo Effect’ upon which Hayek was hanging the remnants of a shredded cycle theory, led Hayek to abandon his cycle theory entirely.
Hayek’s attempted to work a new system in his Pure Theory of Capital (1941), which he originally envisioned as a part of a larger work. In it, he attempted to develop a joint theory of investment and capital. Inexplicably, his 1941 book fell dead-born from the press and proved to be his last substantial effort in the area of theoretical neo-classical economics. Nonetheless, many of the Hayekian capital themes would emerge later in the theory of investment by his students, notably Friedrich and Vera Lutz and Abba Lerner and, more distantly, Trygve Haavelmo.
Hayek turned in 1944 to the political arena with his Road to Serfdom, a polemical defense of laissez-faire – the work for which he is best known outside academia. His subsequent political activities include the foundation of the libertarian ‘Mont Pelerin Society’ in the 1940s.
In 1935, Friedrich Hayek had edited a book on the Socialist Calculation debate in which Mises had been engaged. In resurrecting Barone’s 1908 article, Friedrich Hayek realized that the Mises attack on the socialist position was untenable. As a result, in several famous articles – notably, ‘Economics and Knowledge’ (1937) and ‘On the Use of Knowledge in Society’ (1945) – Hayek composed a response which advanced the ‘Socialist Calculation’ debate to a new level. Succinctly, he claimed, countering Lange and the Paretians, that prices are not merely ‘rates of exchange between goods’, but rather ‘a mechanism for communicating information’ (Hayek, 1945). Friedrich Hayek argued that people have little knowledge of the world beyond their immediate surroundings and this is what forces them to be price-takers – the crucial ingredient that makes the price system work. If, on the other hand, a particular agent’s knowledge were greater, agents would then refuse to act as price-takers but rather make decisions in a way which would manipulate their environment to their advantage thereby destroying the price system. In a complex, uncertain environment, Hayek argument, agents are not able to predict the consequences of their actions, and only this way could the price system work. In Hayek’s words, the “fatal conceit” of the Oskar Lange and other ‘Socialists’ in the calculation debate was that they believed this order could be ‘designed’ by a planner who just gets the prices right, without realising that a price system evolved spontaneously as a result of lack of knowledge. The same limited knowledge which afflicts the agent’s predictive power must necessarily constrain the planner’s as well.
Hayek enhanced this argument with considerations of ‘spontaneous order’ – the idea that a harmonious, evolving order arises from the interaction of a decentralized, heterogeneous group of self-seeking agents with limited knowledge. This order, he claimed, was not “designed” nor could be “designed” by a social planner, even a very wise one, but merely “emerged” or evolved spontaneously from a seemingly complex network of interaction among agents with limited knowledge. Hayek’s elaborations on this complex, evolving spontaneous order are found in various places (e.g. 1952, 1964). Hayek continued with his work on ‘evolving order’, linking it with his work on political and legal theory (e.g. 1960, 1973). In tackling the evolution of political, social, legal and economic institutions, Hayek is rightly conceived as one of the founding fathers of “evolutionary economics”.
In many ways, one can see how the work of the social “evolutionist” and skeptic philosopher, David Hume was particularly influential on Hayek. Indeed, Hayek’s scholarly work on the history of economic thought – e.g. on John Stuart Mill, Richard Cantillon and the Bullionist Debates – often echoed his search for bedfellows in the past, those who had resisted the “rational”, calculable worldviews and simplistic solutions ever-so-present within intellectual circles. In his work on the philosophy of science (1952), Hayek traces the intellectual roots of the rational-socialist tendencies of economics to the theories of Auguste Comte and Saint-Simon in the 19th Century.
Hayek’s efforts were nonetheless ignored in the Keynesian mainstream which then dominated economics. Finding a deaf ear in economics, he looked elsewhere. In an apparently bizarre interlude, Hayek turned his attention to psychology – turning out an anti-behaviorist (and Hume-drenched) tract, The Sensory Order (1952), which fit into his “group selection” type of evolution he had applied to his “spontaneous order” in economics.
All this led to one of his most famous works, the Constitution of Liberty (1960) bringing all his previous work on political theory together into one magnificent defense of “Old Whig” political doctrine and a return attack on the Saint-Simon-Comte collectivism.
Having seen his old idea of a “commodity reserve currency” (1943) fail to generate much interest, Hayek turned in the 1970s to champion the cause of a “free banking system” originally proposed by Vera Smith Lutz and the devolution of monetary control away from the central banks and into the hands of private banks (1978). This drew upon him the opposition of Milton Friedman and the Chicago Monetarists.
After spending many fruitful years at the London School of Economics, Hayek joined the Committee on Social Thought (not the economics department) of the University of Chicago in 1950. In 1962, Hayek left for the University of Freiburg in Germany and subsequently Salzburg, where he spent his remaining years. Friedrich Hayek shared the Nobel Prize with Gunnar Myrdal in 1974 in one of the more controversial and surprising awards ever made (controversial because Myrdal had called for the abolition of the Nobel prize as a result of it having been awarded to Hayek and Milton Friedman, and surprising for, at that time, Hayek was virtually forgotten in the economics profession).
Interest in Friedrich Hayek and his work increased after the 1974 award (his Nobel speech being a reiteration of his Counterrevolution thesis) and has kept on that track until today – his stock being enormously boosted by the collapse of communism in Eastern Europe.
Major Works of Friedrich A. Hayek
The Monetary Policy of the United States After the Recovery from the 1920 Crisis, 1925, ZfVS
Friedrich von Wieser, 1926, JfNS
Intertemporal Price Equilibrium and Movements in the Value of Money, 1928, WWA
Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle , 1929
The Paradox of Saving, 1929, ZfN
Prices and Production, 1931
Reflections on the Pure Theory of Money of Mr. John Maynard Keynes, 1931-1932, Economica
A Note on the Development of the Doctrine of Forced Saving, 1932, QJE
The Present State and Immediate Prospects of the Study of Industrial Fluctuations, 1933, in Spiethoff festschrift
The Trend of Economic Thinking, 1933, Economica
On Neutral Money, 1933
Carl Menger, 1840-1921, 1934, Economica
The Maintenance of Capital, 1935, Economica
Socialist Calculation, two articles in Hayek, 1935, editor, Collectivist Economic Planning
Price Expectations, Monetary Disturbances and Malinvestments, 1935, Nationalokonisk Tidskrift
Richard Cantillon: His life and work, 1936, Revue des Sciences Economiques
Economics and Knowledge, 1937, Economica
Investment that Raises the Demand for Capital, 1937, REStat
Profits, Interest and Investment: And other essays on the theory of industrial fluctuations , 1939
The Socialist Calculation: the competitive solution, 1940, Econometrica
The Pure Theory of Capital , 1941
The Ricardo Effect, 1942, Economica
The Facts of the Social Sciences, 1943, Ethics
A Commodity Reserve Currency, 1943, EJ
The Road to Serfdom, 1944
The Use of Knowledge in Society, 1945, AER
Individualism and Economic Order, 1948
The Intellectuals and Socialism, 1949, U of Chicago Law Review
John Stuart Mill and Harriet Taylor, 1951
The Counter-Revolution of Science: Studies on the abuse of reason, 1952
The Sensory Order: an inquiry into the foundations of theoretical psychology, 1952
Degrees of Explanation, 1955, British Journal for Philosophy of Science
The Dilemma of Specialization, 1956, in White, editor, State of Social Sciences
The Constitution of Liberty, 1960
The Non Sequitur of the Dependence Effect, 1961, Southern EJ
Rules, Perception and Intelligibility, 1962, Proceedings of British Academy
The Economy, Science and Politics, 1963
The Theory of Complex Phenomena, 1964, in Bunge, editor,The Critical Approach to Science and Philosophy
Kinds of Rationalism, 1965, ESQ
Principles of a Liberal Social Order, 1966, Il Politico
Dr. Bernard Mandeville, 1670-1733, 1966, Proceedings of British Academy
The Legal and Political Philosophy of David Hume, 1967, Il Politico
Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Sociology, 1967
Competition as a Discovery Procedure, 1968
The Primacy of the Abstract, 1968
Three Elucidations of the Ricardo Effect, 1969, JPE
A Tiger by the Tail, 1972
Law, Legislation and Liberty, 3 volumes, 1973-1979
The Pretence of Knowledge, 1975, Les Prix Nobel en 1974
Denationalisation of Money: The argument refined, 1978
New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas, 1978
Can We Still Avoid Inflation? (orig. 1970)
Ludwig von Mises, 1977
Toward a Free-Market Monetary System, 1979, J of Libertarian Studies
Money, Capital and Fluctuations: Early essays, 1984
The Fatal Conceit: Or the errors of socialism, 1988
Very interesting points you have noted, regards for posting.
Hello there! This post couldn’t be written much better! Going through this post reminds me of my previous roommate! He always kept preaching about this. I’ll forward this article to him. Pretty sure he will have a good read. Thanks for sharing!
Super-Duper website! I am loving it!! Will come back again. I am bookmarking your feeds also.